®
Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
Author(s): 3ohn W. Meyer and Brian Rowan
Source: The American J’ournai of Socioiogy. Vol. 83. No. 2. (Sep.. 1977). pp. 340-363
Published by: The University of Chicago Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org stable/277X293
Accessed: 20/07/2008 07:45
Your use ofthe JSTOR archive indicares your acceptance ofJSTOR’s Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http:/www.jstor.orgpagc/info about. policies/tenns.jsp. JSTORs Tcrrns and Coriditions oíUse provides. in part, that unlcss you have obtained prior pcrmission, you may not downioad an entire issuc ofajounial or multiple copies ofarticles, and you may use contcnt in Lhe JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-comniercial use.
Please contact Lhe publisher regarding any further use ofthis work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org action/showPublishcr?publisherCodeucprcss.
Each eopy ofany part of a JSTOR transmission must contam the sarne copyright notice that appears on the sereen or printed page of such transmission.
JSTOR is a not-fbr-prolit organization frunded in 1995 Lo huild trusted digital archives for scholarship. Wc work with Lhe scholarly comrnunity to preserve their work and the materiais they rely upon. and te build a common research platform that prornotes lhe discovery and use ofthese resources. For more information abou JSTOR. please contacl supporLjjstor.org.
Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony1
John W. Meyer and Brian Rowan
Stanford University
Many formal organizational structures arise as reflections of ration alized institutional ruies. The elaboration of such rules in modern states and societies accounts in part for the expansion and increased complexity of formal organizational structures. Institutional rules function as myths which organizations incorporate, gaining legitimacy, resources, stability, and enhanced survival prospects. Organizations whose structures become isomorphic with the myths of the institut ional environment—in contrast with those primarily structured by the demands of technical production and exchange—decrease internal coordination and control in order to maintain legitimacy. Structures are decoupled from each other and from ongoing activities. In place of coordination, inspection, and evaluation, a logic of corifidence and good faith is employed.
Formal organizations are generally understood to be systems of coordinated and controlled activities that arise when work is embedded in complex networks of technical relations and boundary-spanning exchanges. But in modern societies formal organizational structures arise in highly institut ionalized contexts. Professions, policies, and programs are created along with the products and services that they are understood to produce rationall y. This permits many new organizations to spring up and forces existing ones to incorporate new practices and procedures. That is, organizations are driven to incorporate the practices and procedures defined by prevailing rationalized concepts of organizational work and institutionalized in society. Organizations that do so increase their legitimacy and their survival prosp ects, independent of the immediate efficacy of the acquired practices and procedures.
Institutionalized products, services, techniques, policies, and programs function as powerful myths, and many organizations adopt them cerem onially. But conformity to institutionalized rules often confiicts sharply
1 Work on this paper was conducted at the Stanford Center for Research and Development in Teaching (SCRDT) and was supported by the National Institute of Education (contract no. NE-C-00-3-0062). The views expressed here do not, of course, reflect NIE positions. Many coileagues in the SCRDT, the Stanford Organizations Training Program, the Americ an Sociological Association’s work group on Organizations and Environments, and the NIE gave help and encouragement. In particular, H. Acland, A. Bergesen, J. Boli-Bennett, T. Deal, J. Freeman, P. Hirsch, J. G. March, W. R. Scott, and W. Starbuck made helpful suggestions.
340 AIS Volume 83 Number 2
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
with efliciency criteria and, conversely, to coordinate and contrai activity in order to promote efficiency undermines an organization’s ceremonial conformity and sacrifices its support and legitimacy. To maintain ceremonial conformity, organizations that reflect institutionai rules tend to buifer their formal structures from the uncertainties of technicai activities by becoming loosely coupled, building gaps between their formal structures and actual work activities.
This paper argues that the formal structures of many organizations in postindustrial society (Beli ‘1973) dramatically reflect the myths of their institutional environments instead of the demands of their work activities. The ftrst part describes prevailing theories of the origins of formal structures and the main problem the theories confront. The second part discusses an alternative source of formal structures: myths embedded in the institutional environment. The third part develops the argument that organizations reflecting institutionalized environments maintain gaps between their formal structures and their ongoing work activities. The final part summ arizes by discussing some research implications.
Throughout the paper, institutionalized rules are distinguished sharply from prevailing social behaviors. Institutionalized rules are classifications built into society as reciprocated typifications or interpretations (Berger and Luckmann 1967, p. 54). Such rules may be simply taken for granted or may be supported by public opinion ar the force of law (Starbuck 1976). Institutions inevitably involve normative obligations but often enter into social life primarily as facts which must be taken into account by actors. Institutionalization involves the processes by which social processes, obligat ions, or actualities come to take on a rulelike status in social thought and action. So, for example, the social status of doctor is a highly institutionalized rule (both normative and cognitive) for managing illness as well as a social role made up of particular behaviors, relations, and expectations. Research and development is an institutionalized category of organizational activity which has meaning and value in many sectors of society, as well as a collect ion of actual research and development activities. In a smaller way, a No Smoking sign is an institution with legal status and implications, as well as an attempt to regulate smoking behavior. It is fundamental to the argument of this paper that institutional rules may have effects on organizational structures and their implementation in actual tecimical work which are very different from the effects generated by the networks of social behavior and relationships which compose and surround a given organization.
PREVAILING THEORIES OF FORMAL STRUCTURE
A sharp distinction should be made between the formal structure of an organization and its actual day-to-day work activities. Formal structure is
341
American Journal of Sociology
a blueprint for activities which includes, first of ali, the table of organization:
a listing of offices, departments, positions, and programs. These elements are linked by explicit goals and policies that make up a rational theory of how, and to what end, activities are to be fitted together. The essence of a modern bureaucratic organization lies in the rationalized and impersonal character of these structurai elements and of the goals that Iink them.
One of the central problems in organization theory is to describe the conditions that give rise to rationalized formal structure. In conventional theories, rational formal structure is assumed to be the most effective way to coordinate and control the complex relational networks involved in modern technical or work activities (see Scott 1975 for a review). This assumption derives from Weber’s (1930, 1946, 1947) discussions of the historical emergence of bureaucracies as consequences of economic markets and centralized states. Economic markets place a premium on rationality and coordination. As markets expand, the relational networks in a given domam become more complex and differentiated, and organizations in that domam must manage more interna! and boundary-spanning interdepend encies. Such factors as size (Blau 1970) and technology (Woodward 1965) increase the complexity of interna! relations, and the division of labor among organizations increases boundary-spanning problems (Aiken and Hage 1968; Freeman 1973; Thompson 1967). Because the need for coordination increases under these conditions, and because formally coordinated work has comp etitive advantages, organizations with rationa!ized formal structures tend to develop.
The formation of centralized states and the penetration of societies by politica! centers also contribute to the rise and spread of formal organization. When the relational networks involved in economic exchange and political management become extremely complex, bureaucratic structures are thought to be the most effective and rational means to standardize and contro! subu nits. Bureaucratic control is especially usefu! for expanding politica! centers, and standardization is often demanded by both centers and periphe ral units (Bendix 1964, 1968). Political centers organize layers of offices that manage to extend conformity and to dispiace traditional activities throughout societies.
The problem. Prevaiing (heoties assume lhal lhe coordination and control of activity are lhe crilical dimenswns on which formal organizalions have succeeded in lhe modern world. This assumption is based on the view that organizations function according to their formal blueprints: coordination is routine, ru!es and procedures are followed, and actual activities conform to the prescript ions of formal structure. But much of the empirical research on organizat ions casts doubt on this assumption. An earlier generation of researchers concluded that there was a great gap between the formal and the informal organization (e.g., Dalton 1959; Downs 1967; Homans 1950). A related
342
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
observation is that formal organizations are often Ioosely coupled (March and Olsen 1976; Weick 1976): structural elements are only loosely linked to each other and to activities, rules are often violated, decisions are often uni mplemented, or if implemented have uncertain consequences, technologies are of problematic efficiency, and evaluation and inspection systems are subverted or rendered so vague as to provide little coordination.
Formal organizations are endemic in modern societies. There is need for an explanation of their risç that is partially free from the assumption that, in practice, formal structures actually coordinate and control work. Such an explanation should account for the elaboration of purposes, positions, policies, and procedural rules that characterizes formal organizations, but must do so without supposing that these structural features are implemented in routine work activity.
INSTITIJTIONAL SOURCES OF FORMAL STRUCTURE
By focusing on the management of complex relational networks and the exercise of coordination and control, prevailing theories have neglected an alternative Weberian source of formal structure: the Iegitimacy of ration alized formal structures. In prevailing theories, legitimacy is a given:
assertions about bureaucratization rest on the assumption of norms of rationality (Thompson 1967). When norms do play causal roles in theories of bureaucratization, it is because they are thought to be built into modern societies and personalities as very general values, which are thought to facilitate formal organization. But norms of rationality are not simply general values. They exist in much more specific and powerful ways in the rules, understandings, and meanings attached to institutionalized social structures. The causal importance of such institutions in the process of bureaucratization has been neglected.
Formal structures are not only creatures of their relational networks in the social organization. In modern societies, the elements of rationalized formal structure are deeply ingrained in, and reflect, widespread understandings of social reality. Many of the positions, policies, programs, and procedures of modern organizations are enforced by public opinion, by the views of important constituents, by knowledge legitimated through the educational system, by social prestige, by the laws, and by the definitions of negligence and prudence used by the courts. Such elements of formal structure are manifestations of powerful institutional rules which function as highly rationalized myths that are binding on particular organizations.
In modern societies, the myths generating formal organizational structure have two key properties. First, they are rationalized and impersonal pres criptions that identify various social purposes as technical ones and specify in a rulelike way the appropriate means to pursue these technical purposes
343
American Journal of Sociology
rationally (Eliul 1964). Second, they are highly institutionalized and thus in some measure beyond the discretion of any individual participant or organization. They must, therefore, be taken for granted as legitimate, apart from evaluations of their impact on work outcomes.
Many elements of formal structure are highly institutionalized and function as myths. Examples include professions, programs, and technologies:
Large numbers of rationalized professions emerge (Wilensky 1965; Beli 1973). These are occupations controlled, not only by direct inspection of work outcomes but also by social ruies of licensing, certifying, and schooiing. The occupations are rationalized, being understood to control impersonal techniques rather than moral mysteries. Further, they are highly institutiona lized: the delegation of activities to the appropriate occupations is socially expected and often legally obiigatory over and above any calculations of its efficiency.
Many formalized organizational programs are also institutionalized in soc iety. Ideologies define the functions appropriate to a business—such as saies, production, advertising, or accounting; to a university—such as instruction and research in history, engineering, and literature; and to a hospital—such as surgery, internal medicine, and obstetrics. Such classifications of organiz ational functions, and the speciflcations for conducting each function, are prefabricated formulae available for use by any given organization.
Similarly, tcchnologies are institutionalized and become myths binding on organizations. Technical procedures of production, accounting, personnel sel ection, or data processing become taken-for-granted means to accomplish organizational ends. Quite apart from their possible efficiency, such institut ionalized techniques establish an organization as appropriate, rational, and modern. Their use displays responsibility and avoids claims of negligence.
The impact of such rationalized institutional elements on organizations and organizing situations is enormous. These mIes define new organizing situations, redefine existing ones, and specify the means for coping rationally with each. They enable, and often require, participants to organize along prescribed lines. And they spread very rapidly in modern society as part of the rise of postindustrial society (BelI 1973). New and extant domains of activity are codified in institutionalized programs, professions, or techniques, and organizations incorporate the packaged cedes. For example:
The discipline of psychology creates a rationalized theory of personnel selection and certifies personnel professionais. Personnel departments and functionaries appear in alI sorts of extant organizations, and new specialized pcrsonnel agencies also appear.
As programs of research and development are created and professionals with expertise in these fields are trained and defined, organizations come under increasing pressure tu incorporate R & D units.
As the prerational profession of prostitution is rationalized along medical lines, bureaucratized organizations—sex-therapy clinics, massage parlors, and the like—spring up more easily.
As the issues of safety and environmentai poliution arise, and as relevant
344
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
professions and programs become institutionaiized in laws, union ideologies, and pubiic opinion, organizations incorporate these programs and prof ess ions.
The growth of rationalized institutional structures in society makes formal organizations more common and more elaborate. Such institutions are myths which make formal organizations both easier to create and more necessary. After ali, the building blocks for organizations come to be littered around the societal landscape; it takes only a little entrepreneurial energy to assembie them into a structure. And because these building blocks are considered proper, adequate, rational, and necessary, organizations must incorporate them to avoid illegitimacy. Thus, the myths built into ration alized institutional elements create the necessity, the opportunity, and the impulse to organize rationally, over and above pressures in this direction created by the need to manage proximate relationai networks:
Proposition 1. As raiionalized inslüutional ruks arise in given domains of work activity, formal organizations form and expand by incorporating lhese rules as siruclural elemenis.
Two distinct ideas are implied here: (lA) As institutionalized myths define new domains of rationalized activity, formal organizations emerge in these domains. (1B) As rationalizing institutional myths arise in existing domains of activity, extant organizations expand their formal structures so as to become isomorphic with these new myths.
To understand the larger historicai procesa it is useful to note that:
Proposition 2. The more modernized lhe society, lhe more extended lhe rationali.zed instilutional siructure in given domains and lhe grealer lhe number of domains containing rationalized institutions.
Modern institutions, then, are thoroughly rationalized, and these ration alized elements act as myths giving rise to more formal organization. When propositions 1 and 2 are combined, two more specific ideas follow: (2A) Formal organizations are more likely to emerge in more modernized societies, even with the complexity of immediate relational networks held constant. (2B) Formal organizations in a given domam of activity are likely to have more elaborated structures in more modernized societies, even with the complexity of immediate relational networks held constant.
Combining the ideas above with prevailing organization theory, it becomes clear that modern societies are fihled with rationalized bureaucracies for two reasons. First, as the prevailing theories have asserted, relational networks become increasingly complex as societies modernize. Second, modern societies are fihled with institutional rules which function as myths depicting various formal structures as rational means to the attainment of desirable ends. Figure 1 summarizes these two iines of theory. Both lines suggest that the postindustrial society—the society dominated by rational organizat ion even more than by the forces of production—arises both out of the
34$
American Journal of Sociology
The prevalence of
rationalized
institutional clemente
presence and
Societal elaboration of
rsoderniat ton formal organizational
structures
The co.plexity of
‘networks of social
organization and
exchenge
FIG. 1 .—The origina and elaboration of formal organizational structures
complexity of the modern social organizational network and, more directly, as an ideological matter. Once institutionalized, rationality becomes a myth with explosive organizing potential, as both Eliul (1964) and Beli (1973)— though with rather different reactions—observe.
The Relation of Organizations to Their Institutional Environments
The observation is not new that organizations are structured by phenomena in their environments and tend to become isomorphic with them. One explanation of such isomorphism is that formal organizations become matched with their environments by technical and exchange interdependenc ies. This une of reasoning can be seen in the works of Aiken and Hage (1968), Hawley (1968), and Thompson (1967). This explanation asserts that structural elements diffuse because environments create boundary-spanning exigencies for organizations, and that organizations which incorporate structural elements isomorphic with the environment are able to manage such interdependencies.
A second explanation for the parallelism between organizations and their environments—and the one emphasized here—is that organizations struct urally reflect socially constructed reality (Berger and Luckmann 1967). This view is suggested in the work of Parsons (1956) and Udy (1970), who see organizations as greatly conditioned by their general institutional environments and therefore as institutions themselves in part. Emery and Trist (1965) also see organizations as responding directly to environmental structures and distinguish such eflects sharply from those that occur through boundary-spanning exchanges. According to the institutional conception as developed here, organizations tend to disappear as distinct and bounded units. Quite beyond the environmental interrelations suggested in opens ystems theories, institutional theories in their extrerne forms define organiz ations as dramatic enactments of the rationalized myths pervading modern societies, rather than as units involved in exchange—no matter how comp lex—with their environments.
346
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
The two explanations of environmental isomorphism are not entirely inconsistent. Organizations both deal with their environments at their boundaries and imitate environmental elements in their structures. However, the two lines of explanation have very different implications for internal organizational processes, as wiIl be argued below.
The Origins of Rational Institutional Myths
Bureaucratization is caused in part by the proliferation of rationalized myths in society, and this in turn invoives the evolution of the whole modern institutional system. Although the latter topic is beyond the scope of this paper, three specific processes that generate rationalized myths of organizat ional structure can be noted.
The e14.zboration of com pkx relational networks.—As the relational networks in societies become dense and interconnected, increasing numbers of ration aiized myths arise. Some of them are highly generalized: for example, the principies of universaiism (Parsons 1971), contracts (Spencer 1897), restitut ion (Durkheim 1933), and expertise (Weber 1947) are generalized to diverse occupations, organizational programs, and organizational practices. Other myths desenhe specific structural elements. These myths may oniginate from narrow contexts and be applied in different ones. For example, in modern societies the relational contexts of business organizations in a single industry are roughly similar from place to place. Under these conditions a particularly effective practice, occupational specialty, or principie of coordination can be codified into mythlike form. The laws, the educational and credentialing systems, and public opinion then make it necessary or advantageous for organizations to incorporate the new structures.
The degree of colkctive organizalion of Lhe environmenL—The myths generated by particular organizational practices and diffused through relational networks have legitimacy based on the supposition that they are rationaily effective. But many myths also have oticiai legitimacy based on legal inandates. Societies that, through nation building and state formation, have developed rational-legal orders are especially prone to give coilective (legal) authority to institutions which legitimate particular organizational structures. The rise of centralized states and integrated nations means that organized agents of society assume jurisdiction over large numbers of activity domains (Swanson 1971). Legislative and judicial authonities create and interpret legal mandates; administrative agencies—such as state and federal governments, port authorities, and school districts—establish rules of practice; and licenses and credentiais become necessary in order to practice occupations. The stronger the rational-legal order, the greater the extent to which rationalized rules and procedures and personnel become
347
American Jourual of Sociology
institutional requirements. New formal organizations emerge and extant organizations acquire new structurai elements.
Leadership efforts of local organizaiions.—The rise of the state and the expansion of coilective jurisdiction are often thought to result in domestic ated organizations (Carison 1962) subject to high leveis of goal displacement (Clark 1956; Seiznick 1949; and Zaid and Denton 1963). This view is misl eading: organizations do often adapt to their institutional contexts, but they often piay active roles in shaping those contexts (Dowling and Pfeffer 1975; Parsons 1956; Perrow 1970; Thompson 1967). Many organizations actively seek charters from coilective authorities and manage to institut ionalize their goais and structures in the ruies of such authorities.
Efforts to moid institutional environments proceed along two dimensions. First, powerful organizations force their immediate relational networks to adapt to their structures and relations. For instance, automobile producers help create demands for particular kinds of roads, transportation systems, and fueis that make automobiles virtual necessities; competitive forms of transportation have to adapt to the existing relational context. But second, powerful organizations attempt to build their goals and procedures directiy into society as institutional rules. Automobile producers, for instance, attempt to create the standards in pubiic opinion defining desirable cars, to influence legal standards defining satisfactory cars, to affect judicial ruies defining cars adequate enough to avoid manufacturer iiabiiity, and to force agents of the collectivity to purchase oniy their cars. Rivais must then compete both in social networks or markets and in contexts of institutional rules which are defined by extant organizations. In this fashion, given organizational forms perpetuate themseives by becoming institutionaiized rules. For example:
School administrators who create new curricuia or training programs att empt to validate them as legitimate innovations in educational theory and governmentai requirements. If they are successful, the new procedures can be perpetuated as authoritatively required or at least satisfactory.
New departments within business enterprises, such as personnel, advertisi ng, or research and deveiopment departments, attempt to professionalize by creating mies of practice and personnel certification that are enforced by the schoois, prestige systems, and the iaws.
Organizations under attack in competitive environments—small farms, passenger railways, or RolIs Royce—attempt to establish themselves as cent ral to the cultural traditions of their societies in order to receive official protection.
The Impact of Institutional Environments on Organizations
Isomorphism with environmental institutions has some crucial consequences for organizations: (a) they incorporate elements which are legitimated externaily, rather than in terms of efliciency; (b) they employ external or
348
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
ceremonial assessment criteria to define the value of structural elements; and (c) dependence on externally fixed institutions reduces turbuience and maintains stability. As a result, it is argued here, institutional isomorphism promotes the success and survival of organizations. Incorporating externally legitimated formal structures increases the commitment of internal particip ants and external constituents. And the use of externa! assessment criteria— that is, moving toward the status in society of a subunit rather than an independent system—can enable an organization to remam successfui by social definition, buffering it from failure.
Changing formal slruclures.—By designing a formal structure that adheres to the prescriptions of myths in the institutional environment, an organizat ion demonstrates that it is acting on collectively valued purposes in a proper and adequate manner (Dowling and Pfeffer 1975; Meyer and Rowan 1975). The incorporation of institutionalized elements provides an account (Scott and Lyman 1968) of its activities that protects the organization from having its conduct questioned. The organization becomes, in a word, legitimate, and it uses its iegitimacy to strengthen its support and secure its survival.
From an institutionai perspective, then, a most important aspect of isomorphism with environmental institutions is the evolution of organizat ional language. The labeis of the organization chart as well as the vocabul ary used to delineate organizational goais, procedures, and policies are analogous to the vocabuiaries of motive used to account for the activities of individuais (BIum and McHugh 1971; Miils 1940). Just as jealousy, anger, altruism, and love are myths that interpret and explain the actions of individuais, the myths of doctors, of accountants, or of the assembiy une expiam organizationai activities. Thus, some can say that the engineers wiil solve a specific problem or that the secretaries will perform certain tasks, without knowing who these engineers or secretaries will be or exactly what they wiIl do. Both the speaker and the listeners understand such statements to describe how certain responsibilities will be carried out.
Vocabularies of structure which are isomorphic with institutional rules provide pnident, rational, and legitimate accounts. Organizations described in legitimated vocabularies are assumed to be oriented to collectively defined, and often collectively mandated, ends. The myths of personnel services, for example, not only account for the rationality of employment practices but also indicate that personnel services are valuable to an organization. Emp loyees, applicants, managers, trustees, and governmental agencies are predisposed to trust the hiring practices of organizations that follow legitim ated procedures—such as equal opportunity programs, or personality testing—and they are more willing to participate in or to fund such organizat ions. On the other hand, organizations that omit environmentally legitim ated elements of structure or create unique structures lack acceptable
349
American Journal of Sociology
legitimated accounts of their activities. Such organizations are more vuinera ble to claims that they are negligent, irrational, or unnecessary. Claims of this kind, whether made by internal participants, external constituents, or the government, can cause organizations to incur real costs. For example:
With the rise of modern medical institutions, large organizations that do not arrange medical-care facilities for their workers come to be seen as neglig ent—by the workers, by management factions, by insurers, by courts which legally define negligence, and often by Iaws. The costs of illegitimacy in ins urance premiums and legal liabilities are very real.
Similarly, environmental safety institutions make it important for organiz ations to create formal safety rules, safety departments, and safety prog rams. No Smoking rules and signs, regardless of their enforcemerit, are necessary to avoid charges of negligence and to avoid the extreme of iliegitim ation: the closing of buildings by the state.
The rise of professionalized economics makes it useful for organizations to incorporate groups of economists and econometric analyses. Though no one may read, understand, or believe them, econometric analyses help legitim ate the organization’s plans in the eyes of investors, customers (as with Defense Department contractors), and internal participants. Such analyses can also provide rational accountings after failures occur: managers whose plans have failed can demonstrate to investors, stockholders, and superiors that procedures were prudent and that decisions were made by rational means.
Thus, rationalized institutions create myths of formal structure which shape organizations. Failure to incorporate the proper elements of structure is negligent and irrational; the continued fiow of support is threatened and internal dissidents are strengthened. At the same time, these myths present organizations with great opportunities for expansion. Affixing Lhe right labeis to activities can change them into valuable services and mobilize the commitments of internal participants and external constituents.
Aiopting externa! assessment criteria.—In institutionally elaborated env ironments organizations also become sensitive to, and employ, external criteria of worth. Such criteria include, for instance, such ceremonial awards as the Nobel Prize, endorsements by important people, the standard prices of professionals and consultants, or the prestige of programs or personnel in external social circles. For example, the conventions of modern accounting attempt to assign value to particular components of organizations on the basis of their contribution—through the organization’s production funct ion—to the goods and services the organization produces. But for many units—service departments, administrative sectors, and others—it is utterly unclear what is being produced that has clear or definable value in terms of its contribution to the organizational product. In these situations, account ants employ shadow prices: they assume that given organizational units are necessary and calculate their value from their prices in the world outside the organization. Thus modern accounting creates ceremonial production
350
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
functions and maps them onto economic production functions: organizations assign externally defined worth to advertising departments, safety departm ents, managers, econometricians, and occasionaily even socioiogists, whether or not these units contribute measurabiy to the production of outputs. Monetary prices, in postindustrial society, reflect hosts of cerem onjal influences, as do economic measures of efficiency, profitability, or net worth (Hirsch 1975).
Ceremonial criteria of worth and ceremonially derived production func-. tions are usefui to organizations: they legitimate organizations with internai participants, stockholders, the pubiic, and the state, as with the IRS or the SEC. They demonstrate socially the fitness of an organization. The inc orporation of structures with high ceremonial value, such as those reflecting the latest expert thinking or those with the most prestige, makes the credit position of an organization more favorable. Loans, donations, or investments are more easily obtained. Finaliy, units within the organization use cerem onjal assessments as accounts of their productive service to the organizat ion. Their internal power rises with their performance on ceremonial measures (Salancik and Pfeffer 1974).
Stabiizalion.—The rise of an elaborate institutional environment stabilizes both external and internal organizational relationships. Centralized states, trade association, unions, professional associations, and coalitions among organizations standardize and stabiiize (see the review by Starbuck 1976).
Market conditions, the characteristics of inputs and outputs, and techn ological procedures are brought under the jurisdiction of institutional meanings and controis. Stabilization also results as a given organization becomes part of the wider coliective system. Support is guaranteed by agreements instead of depending entireiy on performance. For exampie, apart from whether schools educate students, or hospitais cure patients, people and governmental agencies remam committed to these organizat ions, funding and using them almost automatically year after year.
Institutionally controlled environments buifer organizations from turbul ence (Emery and Trist 1965; Terreberry 1968). Adaptations occur less rapidly as increased numbers of agreements are enacted. Coilectively granted monopolies guarantee clienteies for organizations iike schoois, hospitais, or professionai associations. The taken-for-granted (and Iegally regulated) quality of institutionai rules makes dramatjc instabilities in products, techniques, or poiicies uniikely. And legitimacy as accepted subu nits of society protects organizations from immediate sanctions for variat ions in technical performance:
Thus, American school districts (like other governmental units) have near monopolies and are very stable. They must conform to wider rules about proper classifications and credentiais of teachers and students, and of topics of study. But they are protected by rules which make education as defined
351
American Journal of Sociology
by these classifications compulsory. Alternative or private schoois are poss ibie, but must conform so closely to the required structures and classificat ions as to be abie to generate little advantage.
Some business organizations obtain very high leveis of institutional stab iiization. A large defense contractor may be paid for foilowing agreed-on procedures, even if the product is ineifective. In the extreme, such organizat ions may be so successfui as to survive bankruptcy intact—as Lockheed and Penn Central have done—by becoming partially components of the state. More commonly, such firms are guaranteed survival by state-regul ated rates which secure profits regardiess of costs, as with American public utiiity firms.
Large automobile firms are a little less stabiized. They exist in an environm ent that contains enough structures to make automobiles, as conventionaily defined, virtual necessities. But stlll, customers and governments can inspect each automobile and can evaluate and even legally discredit it. Legal action cannot as easily discredit a high schooi graduate.
Organizalional success and survival.—Thus, organizational success depends on factors other than efficient coordination and control of productive activities. Independent of their productive efficiency, organizations which exist in highly elaborated institutional environments and succeed in bec oming isomorphic with these environments gain the legitimacy and res ources needed to survive. In part, this depends on environmental processes and on the capacity of given organizational leadership to mold these processes (Hirsch 1975). In part, it depends on the abiiity of given organizations to conform to, and become iegitimated by, environmentai institutions. In institutionally elaborated environments, sagacious conformity is required:
leadership (in a university, a hospital, or a business) requires an unders tanding of changing fashions and governmental programs. But this kind of conformity—and the almost guaranteed survival which rnay accompany it— is possibie only in an environment with a highly institutionalized structure. 1» such a context an organization can be locked into isomorphisrn, cerem onially refiecting the institutional environment in its structure, funct ionaries, and procedures. Thus, in addition to the conventionally defined sources of organizational success and survival, the foliowing general assertion can be proposed:
Proposition 3. Organizaiwns lhat incorporate socieially legitimaled ration alized ekmenls in (heir formal siructures maximize their legiimacy and increase lheir resources and survival capabiilies.
This proposition asserts that the iong-run survival prospects of organizat ions increase as state structures elaborate and as organizations respond to institutionalized ruies. In the United States, for instance, schools, hospitais, and welfare organizations show considerabie ability to survive, precisely because they are matched with—and almost absorbed by—their institut ional environments. In the sarne way, organizations fail when they deviate
352
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
from the prescriptions of institutionalizing myths: quite apart from technical efliciency, organizations which innovate in important structural ways bear considerable costs in legitimacy.
Figure 2 summarizes the general argument of this section, alongside the establishcd view that organizations succeed through efficiency.
INSTITUTIONALIZED STRUCTURES AND ORGANIZATIONAL ACTIVITIES
Rationalized formal structures arise in two contexts. First, the demands of local relational networks encourage the development of structures that coordinate and control activities. Such structures contribute to the efficiency of organizations and give them competitive advantages over Iess efficient competitors. Second, the interconnectedness of societal relations, the coilective organization of society, and the leadership of organizational elites create a highly institutionalized context. In this context rationalized struct ures present an acceptable account of organizational activities, and organiz ations gain legitimacy, stability, and resources.
AlI organizations, to one degree or another, are embedded in both relat ional and institutionalized contexts and are therefore concerned both with coordinating and controlling their activities and with prudently accounting for them. Organizations in highly institutionalized environments face int ernal and boundary-spanning contingencies. Schools, for example, must transport students to and from school under some circumstances and must assign teachers, students, and topics to classrooms. On the other hand, organizations producing in markets that place great emphasis on efficiency build in units whose relation to production is obscure and whose efficiency is determined, not by a true production function, but by ceremonial definit ion.
Nevertheless, the survival of some organizations depends more on managi ng the demands of internal and boundary-spanning relations, while the survival of others depends more on the ceremonial demands of highly institutionalized environments. The discussion to follow shows that whether an organization’s survival depends primarily on relational or on institutional demands determines the tightness of alignments between structures and activities.
Elaboration of rationalized Organizational coformity
institutional myths with institutional yths
OrganiionaJefficiency
Fio. 2.—Organizational survival
353
American Journal of Sociology
Types of Organizations
Institutionalized myths differ in the completeness with which they describe cause and effect relationships, and in the clarity with which they describe standards that should be used to evaluate outputs (Thompson 1967). Some organizations use routine, clearly defined technologies to produce outputs. When output can be easily evaluated a market often develops, and cons umers gain considerable rights of inspection and control. In this context, efficiency often determines success. Organizations must face exigencies of dose coordination with their relational networks, and they cope with these exigencies by organizing around immediate technical problems.
But the rise of collectively organized society and the increasing interc onnectedness of social relations have eroded many market contexts. Increasingly, such organizations as schools, R & D units, and governmental bureaucracies use variable, ambiguous technologies to produce outputs that are diflicult to appraise, and other organizations with clearly defined techn ologies find themselves unable to adapt to environmental turbulence. The uncertainties of unpredictable technical contingencies or of adapting to environmental change cannot be resolved on the basis of efficiency. Internal participants and external constituents alike cail for institutionalized rules that promote trust and confidence in outputs and buifer organizations from failure (Emery and Trist 1965).
Thus, one can conceive of a continuum along which organizations can be ordered. At one end are production organizations under strong output controis (Ouchi and McGuire 1975) whose success depends on the managem ent of relational networks. At the other end are institutionalized organizat ions whose success depends on the confidence and stability achieved by isomorphism with institutional rules. For two reasons it is important not to assume that an organization’s location on this continuum is based on the inherent technical properties of its output and therefore permanent. First, the technical properties of outputs are socially defined and do not exist in some concrete sense that allows them to be empirically discovered. Second, environments and organizations often redefine the nature of products, services, and technologies. Redefinition sometimes clarifies techniques or evaluative standards. But often organizations and environments redefine the nature of techniques and output so that ambiguity is introduced and rights of inspection and control are lowered. For example, American schools have evolved from producing rather specific training that was evaluated according to strict criteria of efficiency to producing ambiguously defined services that are evaluated according to criteria of certification (Callahan 1962; Tyack 1974; Meyer and Rowan 1975).
354
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
Structural Inconsistencies in Institutionalized Organizations
Two very general problems face an organization if its success depends primarily on isomorphism with institutionalized rules. First, technical activities and demands for efficiency create conflicts and inconsistencies in an institutionalized organization’s efforts to conform to the ceremonial rules of production. Second, because these ceremonial rules are transmitted by myths that may arise from different paris of the environment, the mies may conflict with one another. These inconsistencies make a concern for efficiency and tight coordination and control problematic.
Formal strilctures that celebrate institutionalized myths differ from structures that act efficiently. Ceremonial activity is significant in relation to categorical rules, not in its concrete effects (Merton 1940; March and Simon 1958). A sick worker must be treated by a doctor using accepted medical procedures; whether the worker is treated effectively is less imp ortant. A bus company must service required routes whether or not there are many passengers. A university inust maintain appropriate departments independently of the departments’ enrollments. Activity, that is, has ritual significance: it maintains appearances and validates an organization.
Categorical rules conflict with the logic of efficiency. Organizations often face the dilemma that activities ceiebrating institutionalized rules, although they count as virtuous ceremonial expenditures, are pure costs from the point of view of efficiency. For example, hiring a Nobel Prize winner brings great ceremonial benefits to a university. The celebrated name can lead to research grants, brighter students, or reputational gains. But from the point of view of immediate outcomes, the expenditure Iowers the instructional return per doilar expended and Iowers the university’s abiiity to solve immediate logistical problems. Also, expensive technologies, which bring prestige to hospitals and business firms, may be simply excessive costs from the point of view of immediate production. Similarly, highly professionalized consultants who bring external blessings on an organization are often difficult to justify in terms of improved productivity, yet may be very important in maintaining internal and external Iegitimacy.
Other conflicts between categorical rules and efficiency arise because institutional rules are couched at high leveis of generalization (Durkheim 1933) whereas technical activities vary with specific, unstandardized, and possibly unique conditions. Because standardized ceremonial categories must confront technical variations and anomalies, the generalized rules of the institutional environment are often inappropriate to specific situations. A governmentally mandated curriculum may be inappropriate for the students at hand, a conventional medical treatment may make little sense given the characteristics of a patient, and federal safety inspectors may intolerably delay boundary-spanning exchanges.
355
American Journal of Sociology
Yet another source of conflict between categorical rules and efficiency is the inconsistency among institutionaiized eiements. Institutionai environm ents are often piuralistic (Udy 1970), and societies promulgate sharply inconsistent myths. As a resuit, organizations in search of external support and stability incorporate ali sorts of incompatible structural elements. Professions are incorporated although they make overlapping jurisdictionai ciaims. Programs are adopted which contend with each other for authority over a given domam. For instance, if one inquires who decides what curricula will be taught in schools, any number of parties from the various governm ents down to individual teachers may say that they decide.
In institutionalized organizations, then, concern with the efficiency of day-to-day activities creates enormous uncertainties. Specific contexts highl ight the inadequacies of the prescriptions of generaiized myths, and incons istent structural elements conflict over jurisdictional rights. Thus the organization must struggle to iink the requirements of ceremonial eiements to technical activities and to link inconsistent ceremoniai eiements to each other.
Resolving Inconsistencies
There are four partiai solutions to these inconsistencies. First, an organizat ion can resist ceremonial requirements. But an organization that neglects ceremonial requirements and portrays itself as efficient may be unsuccessful in documenting its efficiency. Also, rejecting ceremonial requirements negiects an important source of resources and stability. Second, an organizat ion can maintain rigid conformity to institutionalized prescriptions by cutting off external relations. Aithough such isolation upholds ceremonial requirements, internal participants and external constituents may soon become disillusioned with their inability to manage boundary-spanning exchanges. Institutionaiized organizations must not only conform to myths but must also maintain the appearance that the myths actuaiiy work. Third, an organization can cynically acknowledge that its structure is inconsistent with work requirements. But this strategy denies the validity of institut ionalized myths and sabotages the legitimacy of the organization. Fourth, an organization can promise reform. People may picture the present as unworkable but the future as fihled with promising reforms of both structure and activity. But by defining the organization’s valid structure as lying in the future, this strategy makes the organization’s current structure iliegitim ate.
Instead of relying on a partial solution, however, an organization can resolve conflicts between ceremonial rules and efficiency by employing two interrelated devices: decoupiing and the Iogic of confidence.
Decoupling.—Ideally, organizations buiit around efficiency attempt to
356
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
maintain dose alignments between structures and activities. Conformity is enforced through inspection, output quality is continuaily monitored, the efficiency of various units is evaiuated, and the various goals are unified and coordinated. But a policy of dose alignment in institutionalized organizat ions merely makes public a record of inefficiency and inconsistency.
Institutionalized organizations protect their formal structures from evaluation on the basis of technical performance: inspection, evaluation, and control of activities are minimized, and coordination, interdependence, and mutual adjustments among structural units are handied informally.
Proposition 4. Because alienipts to control and coordinate activities in instilulionalized organiza&ms kad to conflicis and loss of legitimacy, ele,nents of structure are decoupled from activilies and froin each other.
Some welI-known properties of organizations illustrate the decoupling process:
Activities are performed beyond the purview of managers. In particular, organizations actively encourage professionalism, and activities are delegated to professionals.
Goals are made ambiguous or vacuous, and categorical ends are substituted for technical ends. HospitaIs treat, not cure, patients. Schools produce stud ents, not learning. In fact, data on technical performance are eliminated or rendered invisibie. Hospitais try to ignore information on cure rates, public services avoid data about effectiveness, and schools deemphasize measures of achievement.
Integration is avoided, program implementation is neglected, and inspect ion and evaluation are ceremonialized.
Human relations are made very important. The organization cannot form ally coordinate activities because its formal rules, if applied, would generate inconsistencies. Therefore individuals are left to work out technical interd ependencies informally. The ability to coordinate things in vioiation of the rules—that is, to get along with other people—is highly valued.
The advantages of decoupling are clear. The assumption that formal structures are realiy working is buffered from the inconsistencies and anomalies involved in technical activities. Also, because integration is avoided disputes and conflicts are minimized, and an organization can mobilize support from a broader range of external constituents.
Thus, decoupiing enables organizations to mahtain standardized, legitim ating, formal structures whiie their activities vary in response to practical considerations. The organizations in an industry tend to be similar in formal structure—reflecting their common institutional origins—but may show much diversity in actual practice.
The logic of contidence and good faith.—Despite the iack of coordination and control, decoupled organizations are not anarchies. Day-to-day activities proceed in an orderiy fashion. What iegitimates institutionalized organizat ions, enabling them to appear useful in spite of the lack of technical valida-
357
Arnerican Journal of Sociology
tion, is the confidence and good faith of their internal participants and their externa! constituents.
Considerations of face characterize ceremonial management (Goffman 1967). Confidence in structural elements is maintained through three practices—avoidance, discretion, and overlooking (Goffman 1967, pp. 12— 18). Avoidance and discretion are encouraged by decoupling autonomous subunits; overlooking anomalies is also quite common. Both interna! participants and external constituents cooperate in these practices. Assuring that individual participants maintain face sustains confidence in the organiz ation, and ultimately reinforces confidence in the myths that rationalize the organization’s existence.
Delegation, professionalization, goal ambiguity, the elimination of output data, and maintenance of face are alI meclianisms for absorbing uncertainty while preserving the formal structure of the organization (March and Simon 1958). They contribute to a general aura of confidence within and outside the organization. Although the literature on informal organization often treats these practices as mechanisms for the achievement of deviant and subgroup purposes (Downs 1967), such treatment ignores a critical feature of organization life: effectively absorbing uncertainty and maint aining confidence requires people to assume that everyone is acting in good faith. The assumption that things are as they seem, that employees and managers are performing their roles properly, allows an organization to perform its daily routines with a decoupled structure.
Decoupling and maintenance of face, in other words, are mechanisms that maintain the assumption that people are acting in good faith. Professionalizat ion is not merely a way of avoiding inspection—it binds both supervisors and subordinates to act in good faith. So in a smaller way does strategic leniency (BIau 1956). And so do the public displays of morale and satisfaction which are characteristic of many organizations. Organizations employ a host of mechanisms to dramatize the ritual commitments which their participants make to basic structural elements. These mechanisms are especially common in organizations which strongly reflect their institut ionalized environments.
Proposition 5. The more an organization’s slruclure is derioedfrom institul ionalized myths, lhe more it mainlains elaborate dispkys of confidence, satisfact ion, and goodfaith, inlernally and exlernaliy.
The commitments built up by displays of morale and satisfaction are not simply vacuous affirmations of institutionalized myths. Participants not only commit themselves to supporting an organization’s ceremonial facade but also commit themselves to making things work out backstage. The committed participants engage ii informal coordination that, although often formally inappropriate, keeps technical activities running smoothly and avoids public embarrassments. In this sense the confidence and good faith
358
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
generated by ceremonial action is in no way fraudulent. It may even be the most reasonabie way to get participants to make their best efforts in situat ions that are made problematic by institutionaiized myths that are at odds with immediate technical demands.
Ceremonial inspection and evaluation.—Aii organizations, even those maintaining high leveis of confidence and good faith, are in environments that have institutionalized the rationalized rituais of inspection and evaluat ion. And inspection and evaluation can uncover events and deviations that undermine legitimacy. So institutionaiized organizations minimize and ceremonialize inspection and evaluation.
In institutionaiized organizations, in fact, evaluation accompanies and produces iliegitimacy. The interest in evaiuation research by the American federal government, for instance, is partly intended to undercut the state, local, and private authorities which have managed social services in the United States. The federal authorities, of course, have usually not evaiuated those programs which are completely under federal jurisdiction; they have only evaluated those over which federal controis are incompiete. Similarly, state governments have often insisted on evaluating the special fundings they create in welfare and education but ordinarily do not evaiuate the programs which they fund in a routine way.
Evaluation and inspection are public assertions of societai control which violate the assumption that everyone is acting with competence and in good faith. Vioiating this assumption lowers moraie and confidence. Thus, evaluation and inspection undermine the ceremonial aspects of organizat ions.
Proposition 6. Instiiukonalized organizaiion seek lo minimize inspeclion and evaluoJion by bolh interna! managers and externa! constiluenis.
Decoupling and the avoidance of inspection and evaluation are not mereiy devices used by the organization. Extemal constituents, too, avoid inspecting and controliing institutionalized organizations (Meyer and Rowan 1975). Accrediting agencies, boards of trustees, government agencies, and individuaIs accept ceremonially at face value the credentiais, ambiguous goals, and categorical evaluations that are characteristic of ceremonial organizations. In elaborate institutional environments these external constit uents are themseives likely to be corporatdy organized agents of society. Maintaining categoricai relationships with their organizational subunits is more stabie and more certain than is relying on inspection and control.
Figure 3 summarizes the main arguments of this section of our discussion.
SUMMARY AND RESEARCH IMPLICATIONS
Organizational structures are created and made more eiaborate with the rise of institutionalized myths, and, in highly institutionalized contexts,
359
American Journal of Sociology
Tbe decoupling of atructural aubunita fro. each other and fro. activity
Iao.orpbiae with an
____________ Rituala of confidence and
elaborated inetitutional ood faith
environ.ent
The avoidance of inspection
and effective evaluation
FIG. 3.—The effects of institutional isomorphism on organizations
organizational action must support these myths. But an organization must also attend to practical activity. The two requirements are at odds. A stable solution is Lo maintain the organization in a loosely coupled state.
No position is taken here on the overail social effectiveness of isomorphic and loosely coupled organizations. To some extent such structures buifer activity from efficiency criteria and produce ineffectiveness. On the other hand, by binding participants to act in good faith, and to adhere to Lhe larger rationalities of the wider structure, they may maximize long-run effective.n ess. It should not be assumed that the creation of microscopic rationalities in the daily activity of workers effects social ends more efllciently than commitment Lo larger institutional claims and purposes.
Research Implications
The argument presented here generates several major theses that have clear research implications.
1. Environments and environmental domains which have institutionalized a greater number of rational myths generate more formal organization. This thesis leads to the research hypothesis that formal organizations rise and become more complex as a result of the rise of Lhe elaborated state and other institutions for coilective action. This hypothesis should hold true even when economic and technical development are held constant. Studies could trace the diffusion to formal organizations of specific institutions:
professions, clearly labeled programs, and the like. For instance, the effects of the rise of theories and professions of personnel selection on the creation of personnel departments in organizations could be studied. Other studies could follow the diffusion of saies departments or research and development departments. Organizations should be found to adapt to such environmental changes, even if no evidence of their effectiveness exists.
Experimentally, one could study the impact on the decisions of organizat ional managers, in planning or altering organizational structures, of hypot hetical variations in environmental institutionalization. Do managers plan differently if they are informed about the existence of established occupations or programmatic institutions in their environments? Do they plan differently
360
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
if they are designing organizations for more or less institutionally elaborated environments?
2. Organizations which incorporate institutionalized myths are more legitimate, successful, and likely to survive. Here, research should compare similar organizations in different contexts. For instance, the presence of personnel departments or research and development units should predict success in environments in which they are widely institutionalized. Organizat ions which have structural elements not institutionalized in their environm ents shouid be more likeiy to fail, as such unauthorized complexity must be justified by claims of efliciency and effectiveness.
More generally, organizations whose claims to support are based on evaluations should be less likely to survive than those which are more highly institutionalized. An implication of this argument is that organizations existing in a highly institutionalized environment are generally more likely to survive.
Experimentally, one could study the size of the loans banks would be wiliing to provide organizations which vary only in (1) the degree of environm ental institutionalization, and (2) the degree to which the organization structurally incorporates environmental institutions. Are banks willing to lend more money to firms whose plans are accompanied by econometric projections? And is this tendency greater in societies in which such project ions are more widely institutionalized?
3. Organizational control efforts, especially in highly institutionaiized contexts, are devoted to ritual conformity, both internally and externally. Such organizations, that is, decouple structure from activity and structures from each other. The idea here is that the more highly institutionalized the environment, the more time and energy organizational elites devote to managing their organization’s public image and status and the iess they devote to coordination and to managing particular boundary-spanning relationships. Further, the argument is that in such contexts managers devote more time to articulating internal structures and relationships at an abstract or ritual levei, in contrast to managing particular relationships among activities and interdependencies.
Experimentally, the time and energy allocations proposed by managers presented with differently described environments could be studied. Do managers, presented with the description of an elaborately institutionalized environment, propose to spend more energy maintaining ritual isomorphism and lesa on monitoring internal conformity? Do they tend to become ina ttentive to evaluation? Do they elaborate doctrines of professionalism and good faith?
The arguments here, in other words, suggest both comparative and experimental studies examining the effects on organizational structure and
361
American Journal of Sociology
coordination of variations in the institutional structure of the wider environm ent. Variations in organizational structure among societies, and within any society across time, are central to this conception of the problem.
REFERENCES
Aiken, Michael, and Jerald Hage. 1968. “Organizational Interdependence and Intra-org anizational Structure.” American Sociotogicoi Review 33 (December): 912—30.
BelI, Daniel. 1973. The Coming of Post-indu.striai Society. New York: Basic. Bendix, Reinhard. 1964. Nakn-Building and Citizen.hip. New York: Wiley.
1968. “Bureaucracy.” Pp. 206—19 in Inlernaiionoi Encyclo pedia oJ ihe Social Scie nces, edited by David L. Silis. New York: Macmillan.
Berger, Peter L., and Thomas Luckmann. 1967. The Social Consiruction of Reaiity. New York: Doubleday.
Blau, Peter M. 1956. Bureaucracy ia Modern Society. New York: Random House. 1970. “A Formal Theory of Differentiation in Organizations.” Anse,*an Sociologic al Revicu 35 (April): 201—18.
Bium, Alan F., and Peter McHugh. 1971. “The Social Ascription of Motives.” Amencan Sociologicol Review 36 (December): 98-109.
Callahan, Raymond E. 1962. Educaion and tke Cedt of Ejlciency. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Carlson, Richard O. 1962. Executiie Swce.ssion and Organizoiional Change. Chicago: Midw est Administration Center, University of Chicago.
Clark, Burton R. 1956. Aduli Educaiwn ia Transition. Berkeley: University of California Presa.
Dalton, MelvilIe. 1959. Men Who Manage. New York: Wiley.
Dowling, John, and Jeffrey Pfeffer. 1975. “Organizational Legitimacy.” Pacific SociologicoJ Review 18 (January): 122—36.
Downs, Anthony. 1967. Inside Bw’eaucracy. Boston: Little, Brown.
Durkheim, Êmile. 1933. The Dit’iSÍOn of La4or in Society. New York: Macmillan. ElIul, Jacques. 1964. Tke Technoiogical Society. New York: Knopf.
Emery, Fred L., and Eric L. Trist. 1965. “The Causal Texture of Organizational Environm ents.” Human ReloAions 18 (February): 2 1—32.
Freeman, John Henry. 1973. “Environment, Technology and Administrative Intensity of Manufacturing Organizations.” American Sociologicoj Review 38 (December): 750-63.
Goffman, Erving. 1967. Intero4ioa RüuoJ. Garden City, N.Y.: Anchor.
Hawley, Amos H. 1968. “Human Ecology.” Pp. 328-37 in Iniernational Encyclopedia of lhe Social Sciences, edited by David L. Sills. New York: Macmillan.
Hirsch, Paul M. 1975. “Organizational Effectiveness and the Institutional Environment.” Administrative Sciencc Quarte,ly 20 (September): 327—44.
Homans, George C. 1950. The Human Group. New York: Harcourt, Brace. March, James G., and Johan P. Olsen. 1976. Ambiguily and Choice ia Organizations. Berg en: Universitetsforlaget.
March, James G., and Herbert A. Simon. 1958. Organizalions. New York: Wiley. Merton, Robert K. 1940. “Bureaucratic Structure and Personality.” Social Forces 18 (May): 560-68.
Meyer, John W., and Brian Rowan. 1975. “Notes on Lhe Structure of Educational Organiz ations.” Papar presented at annual meeting of Lhe American Sociological Association, San Francisco.
Mills, C. Wright. 1940. “Situated Actions and Vocabularies of Motive.” Amuican Sociot ogical Reeiew 5 (February): 904—13.
Ouchi, William, and Mary Ann Maguire. 1975. “Organizational Control: Two Functions.” Administrativa Science Quarterly 20 (December): 559-69.
Parsons, Talcott. 1956. “Suggestions for a Sociological Approach to the Theory of Organiz ations L” Administrative Science Quarterty 1 (June): 63—85.
362
Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony
1971. Tke System of Modern Socie1ies. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hail.
Perrow, Charles. 1970. OrganizoÀional Anoiysi.s: A SocioiogicoJ View. Belmont, Calif.:
Wadsworth.
Salancik, Gerald R., and Jeffrey Pfeffer. 1974. “The Bases and Use of Power in Organizat ional Decision Making.” Administrajive Science Quarlerly 19 (December): 453—73.
Scott, Marvin B., and Stanford M. Lyman. 1968. “Accounts.” American Sociological Rev iew 33 (February): 46-62.
Scott, W. Richard. 1975. “Organizational Structure.” Pp. 1—20 in AnnuoJ Reviei.v ofSociolo gy. Vol. 1, edited by Alex Inkeles. Palo Alto, Calif.: Annual Reviews.
Sebnick, Philip. 1949. TVA and lhe Grass Rools. Berkeley: University of California Presa.
Spencer, Herbert. 1897. Principies oJSociotogy. New York: Appleton.
Starbuck, William H. 1976. “Organizations and their Environments.” Pp. 1069—1123 in Ilandbook of Industrial and Organizational Psychotogy, edited by Marvin D. Dunnette. New York: Rand McNally.
Swanson, Guy E. 1971. “An Organizational Analysis of Coilectivities.” American Sociol ogical Review 36 (August): 607—24.
Terreberry, Shirley. 1968. “The Evolution of Organizational Environments.” Administra- tive Science Quarlerly 12 (March): 590—613.
Thompson, James D. 1967. Organizo.tions in Action. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Tyack, David B. 1974. The One BesI System. Cambndge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Udy, Stanley H., Jr. 1970. Work in Tradi4ional and Modere Socie1y. Englewood Cliffs, N.J. Prentice-Hail.
Weber, Max. 1930. The Prol esLanl’s Ethic and lhe Spirit of Capilalisin. New York: Scribner’s. 1946. Essays in Sociology. New York: Oxford University Presa.
1947. The Theory of Social and &onomi.c Organization. New York: Oxford Univ ersity Presa.
Weick, Karl E. 1976. “Educational Organizations as Loosely Coupled Systems.” Administ rative Science Quarterly 21 (March): 1—19.
Wilensky, Harold L. 1965. “The Professionalization of Everyone?” A merican lournal of Sociology 70 (September): 137—58.
Woodward, Joan. 1965. Industrial Organiza.tion, Theory and Practice. London: Oxford Univ ersity Presa.
Zald, Mayer N., and Patricia Denton. 1963. “From Evangelism to General Service: The Transforniation of the YMCA.” Administro4ive Science Qua,terly 8 (September): 214—34.
363
Assinar:
Postar comentários (Atom)
Nenhum comentário:
Postar um comentário